Social stratification around the NSFAS threshold: A dynamic approach to profiling the missing middle

24th March 2022 By: Econ3x3

Social stratification around the NSFAS threshold: A dynamic approach to profiling the missing middle

In 2018, government announced that the National Student Financial Aid Scheme (NSFAS) would fund all eligible post-school students whose household income was R350 000 or less. The Department of Higher Education and Training is now focusing on what it calls the “missing middle” – students who come from households whose income is too high to make the NSFAS threshold but too low to afford fees –between R350 000 and R600 000. Guided by the poverty dynamics literature, we show that the “missing middle” is a complex category, comprising two distinct groups based on their relative economic stability or vulnerability. A key consideration for how we understand socio-economic need – on both sides of the NSFAS threshold – should reflect the household circumstances that generate economic vulnerability, not only household income at a given point in time.

Setting the scene

Following a change in funding policy in 2018, financially eligible post-school students, whose combined household income is R350 000 per annum or less, are awarded full bursaries through the National Student Financial Aid Scheme (NSFAS). However, recent attention has focused on the lack of affordability of post-school education for the missing middle – a group colloquially defined as those whose household income levels are too low for them to afford fees, but too high to meet the NSFAS income threshold for funding eligibility. Missing middle students are currently considered those whose household income is between R350 000 and R600 000 per annum. The Department of Higher Education and Training (DHET) aims to increase the number of NSFAS beneficiaries by 43% by 2024, working towards a financial aid system that is inclusive of the missing middle.

That said, the sustainability of the present funding model is currently under scrutiny. The design of a sustainable, comprehensive, and progressive financial aid scheme for the future requires a thorough deliberation of the complexities that affect access to post-school education. If free education for all students is not viable, a policy that differentiates students according to socio-economic need could be on the table. Therefore, recognising that there is a distribution of household circumstances both below the current NSFAS threshold, and within the missing middle, is necessary.

One possible approach to differentiating socio-economic need would be to simply consider the household circumstances of those on either side of a household income threshold. However, guided by the poverty dynamics literature, we argue that economic stability – or lack thereof – is a key dimension off which to differentiate households, because it affects the type of decisions that individuals make. Relatively more secure and stable households are better able to absorb risk and plan for the future.

Mobility over time is associated with measurable differences in household characteristics related to economic security and stability. Thus a second approach to differentiating socio-economic need recognises that mobility patterns, as well as current living standards, are important considerations for policy tools. We thus propose a framework that takes account of mobility around the current NSFAS household income eligibility threshold, and not only current income status. This approach recognises that an individual's household income position relative to a threshold can change and is linked to economic stability – or lack thereof. Such an approach allows us to profile the characteristics of households in a way that could be useful for considering a differentiated approach to funding.

Our aim is not so much to make a policy recommendation, but rather to highlight the socio-economic circumstances of South African households in relation to the current threshold to inform and provide context to complex policy considerations.

Conceptualising a funding stratification schema

In Figure 1, we illustrate our strategy for classifying individuals based on their vulnerability to their household income remaining below or falling below the funding threshold. The left column shows conventional policy classes, typically used to reference groups in the post-school funding policy environment. The middle and right columns show how we re-conceptualise funding classes, based on the conditional probability that an individual's household income moves above or falls below the threshold within a two-year period. These probabilities are predicted using coefficient estimates from a multivariate probit regression fit to nationally representative panel data, collected approximately every two years between 2008 and 2017. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first study to apply an income dynamics approach to studying funding thresholds, while addressing simultaneously the endogeneity of initial conditions and panel attrition.

Figure 1: Proposed stratification based on current household circumstances and future mobility

We propose five classifications: Those whose household income is below the R350 000 threshold are divided into those we term (1) ‘persistently eligible’ and (2) ‘transiently eligible’, in relation to the NSFAS definition based on household income. Those who are persistently eligible face below average probabilities of their household income moving above R350 000 within two years, whereas those who are transiently eligible face above average probabilities of their household income exceeding R350 000 within two years. The persistently eligible are thus a relatively more vulnerable group than those that are transiently eligible.

Those in the missing middle are classified as either (3) ‘vulnerable missing middle’ or (4) ‘stable missing middle.’ We use the term ‘stable’ to capture the idea of relative non-vulnerability. Those whom we classify as vulnerable missing middle face above average probabilities of their household income falling below R350 000 within two years. Those whom we term stable missing middle have lower than average probabilities of their household income falling below this level within two years. Lastly, (5) the elite are defined as having household income of more than R600 000 per annum (when initially observed).

Locating the current funding threshold in the income distribution

In 2018, the NSFAS household income threshold for eligibility was extended from roughly R122 000 to R350 000. Figure 2a locates these NSFAS funding thresholds in the South African 2017 national household income distribution. It is apparent that most households fall below the R350 000 threshold (91%), with a small number (5%) remaining in the missing middle (between R350 000 and R600 000).

In Figure 2b, we refine the classification of households by taking economic (in)stability into account. The household income distribution of the persistently eligible and the transiently eligible is distinct, indicating that the transiently eligible are better off, on average, in terms of household income. On the other hand, the income distribution of the vulnerable and stable missing middle groups is similar. However, there is compelling variation in household circumstances among the missing middle that speaks to relative economic vulnerability and stability.

Profiling the NSFAS eligible and the missing middle

Table 1 summarises individuals’ average household characteristics and characteristics of their household head, by funding class:

Table 1 Average characteristics of the household and household head by funding class

Table 1 indicates that between 2008 and 2017, 60% of the population is classified as persistently eligible for NSFAS by our stratification schema. That is, just under two thirds of the population face an above average likelihood of their household income remaining below R350 000 per annum within two years. The average per-capita expenditure of those in the persistently eligible group is just R877.44 per month, situating the average individual in this group below the upper-bound poverty line. Moreover, less than a third of working-age adults in these households hold some form of employment. While we term those in the missing middle who face economic precarity (because of an increased likelihood that their household income may fall below the NSFAS threshold) the ‘vulnerable’ missing middle, our results show that there is substantial vulnerability below the funding threshold that differs from the vulnerability facing those in the missing middle.

The 31% whom we classify as transiently eligible for NSFAS appears to face relatively better circumstances than those persistently eligible – a key distinction is the higher share of household income from the labour market (70% for the transiently eligible vs. 39% for the persistently eligible) – but these circumstances are nonetheless quite distinct from the stable missing middle and the elite groups. Some similarity between the transiently eligible and the vulnerable missing middle is to be expected, since these groups are those whose household income is most likely to churn around the funding threshold. However, Table 1 makes it apparent that those who are transiently eligible are, in some respects, distinct from the vulnerable missing middle group. For example, more than double the share in the vulnerable missing middle live with someone who has a home loan or bond compared with those who are transiently eligible (9% vs. 24%), and over three times the share in the vulnerable missing middle live with someone who has accessed vehicle finance (8% vs. 29%). These results suggests that the current policy is relatively well targeted to the most vulnerable households.

We further observe that the missing middle seems to comprise two distinct groups, despite their income distributions appearing similar. A key motivation for our approach is that by focussing purely on income thresholds, we can risk mis-identifying a share of the population whose household income puts them in a given class (e.g. the missing middle) but who nevertheless still face relative economic insecurity or vulnerability. The share of the missing middle with access to a home loan or bond in their household is 38% (not shown here). However, as Table 1 highlights, more than half the individuals in the stable missing middle live in a household where a resident has a home loan or bond, but this share is less than a quarter for those in the vulnerable missing middle. Our results show that aggregating household circumstances within the missing middle overstates the well-being of vulnerable individuals and understates the relative well-being of those we classify as more economically secure.

Table 1 also shows that the vulnerable missing middle is characterised by relatively lower ownership of assets, inferior access to credit, and less attachment to the labour market than those classified as the stable missing middle. Individuals in the stable missing middle live in smaller households with fewer dependents (both children and elderly) and are relatively more connected to the labour market. Moreover, the fact that the stable missing middle has such a high share of household heads with post-school education is relevant since first-hand experience of application and enrolment could facilitate access. In many respects, the stable middle class more closely resembles the elite, on average, compared with the vulnerable missing middle. We highlight these findings not to suggest that those in the missing middle do not face barriers to access, but rather to prompt a reflection about differentiated targeting of policy.

Conclusion

A key policy priority currently is to establish a sustainable, comprehensive, and progressive financial aid scheme to fund students enrolled in post-school education – a basis for economic empowerment and upliftment. If free education for all students is not viable, a differentiated policy might be necessary. The value in our approach lies in highlighting the concepts of mobility, vulnerability, and economic stability to differentiate the socio-economic circumstances of households in the context of the current post-school funding policy. While income thresholds are always likely to exist for operational purposes in a social support environment, our work shows that when considering the design of support, 1) the current NSFAS funding threshold should not be lowered – it is well targeted at the those living in the most vulnerable households, and 2) when considering extending support to the missing middle, a differentiated funding instrument could work. This group is more likely to be engaged in formal credit markets, for example. That said, we show that economic vulnerability manifests on either side of the current NSFAS funding threshold and acknowledge that economic instability can be an important constraint to post-school access – even when income is above the threshold.

Written by Emma Whitelaw, Nicola Branson & Murray Leibbrandt for Econ3x3